公 法 评 论 http://www.gongfa.com/
THE
LAW VERSUS THE MARKETPLACE:
SPONTANEOUS
ORDER IN JONSON'S BARTHOLOMEW FAIR
Paul A.
Cantor
i.
At first
glance, Ben Jonson's Bartholomew Fair may seem to
be the
Seinfeld of the English Renaissance--the comedy about
nothing. One
can imagine the befuddled looks Jonson got when he
first pitched
the concept to London theatre companies: "I've
written a
play about Bartholomew Fair--a bunch of people go to
the fair,
they mill around, and then they go home." Compared to
Jonson's
earlier comic masterpieces, Volpone and The Alchemist,
Bartholomew
Fair seems unfocused and diffuse.1 It
lacks a pair
of central
characters around whom the play is organized and who
appear to
direct its action, like Volpone and Mosca in Volpone or
Face and
Subtle in The Alchemist.2 The
play is constantly
threatening
to veer off into irrelevance, incoherence, and even
absurdity, as
the characters get wrapped up in word games that
fly in the
face of normal dramatic logic. Just as in Seinfeld,
the
characters often appear to be talking merely to fill the time
and not
because they have anything in particular to talk about.
But
Bartholomew Fair only appears to be about nothing.
Again like
Seinfeld, the play tells us something about its
characters by
showing them engaged in so much meaningless
dialogue. And
its apparent formlessness and lack of a center
reflect a
deeper order and sense of form. By liberating the
dialogue from
the normal constraints of dramatic action, Jonson
2
freed himself
to put an unparalleled slice of Renaissance life on
the stage.
What may at first seem to be a weakness of
Bartholomew
Fair--its lack of focus--turns out to be its great
strength--its
ability to embrace a wide variety of human types
and develop
them in their full diversity, without imposing any
narrowing
artistic or moral conceptions upon them.
Jonson's play
is thus deeply paradoxical. Though a highly
artful play,
it succeeds in concealing its artifice and may at
first seem to
be just thrown together on the stage like an
improvisation.3 Though seemingly the most formless of
Jonson's
plays, it
actually obeys the unities of time and place as
strictly as
any of his other works.4 Remarkably,
in Bartholomew
Fair Jonson
found a way of remaining within the bounds of his
neoclassical
conception of dramatic form, while still imparting a
feeling of
spontaneity to the play. In short, the play obeys
Jonson's
cherished law of the unities, while appearing to be
wholly free
and above or beyond any formal law.5
The tension
between law and spontaneity evident in the form
of Bartholomew
Fair turns out to be at work in the content as
well. Despite
ostensibly being about nothing, Bartholomew Fair
is of course
really about Bartholomew Fair, one of the great
marketplaces
of Renaissance London.6 Throughout
his career,
Jonson was
fascinated by the emerging market economy in
Renaissance
Europe. He was intrigued by the new categories of
3
human
identity the market was creating (the roles of merchants,
bankers,
financiers, and entrepreneurs) and he was evidently
troubled by
the new forms of corruption and vice endemic to
proto-capitalist
life. Bartholomew Fair gave Jonson a chance to
anatomize the
lawlessness of the marketplace. Through the
comments of
his Puritan characters, Jonson shows how the fair
violates religious
law, and he uses Adam Overdo, a Justice of the
Peace, to
rail against the ways the merchants continually violate
the criminal
law as well. As Jonson presents it, Bartholomew
Fair is the
original home and headquarters of all the charlatans,
cheaters, and
thieves in London.
And yet,
strangely enough, for all his criticism of the
marketplace
in Bartholomew Fair, Jonson ends up being more
critical of
its critics.7
From the standpoint of
traditional
religion and
politics, the market may look lawless, but Jonson at
least
explores the possibility that it may obey laws of its own.
In a
remarkable anticipation of free market economics, he
appears to
sense that the market may be a self-regulating
mechanism,
capable of bringing peace to a society that seems
otherwise to
be tearing itself apart in religious and political
conflicts.
The characters who stand up for religious and
political
principles in Bartholomew Fair turn out to be the
divisive
forces in the play, while the seemingly lawless
participants
in the fair work to bring about a kind of civil
4
harmony,
based on the satisfaction of basic economic needs and
natural human
desires. Jonson exposes all the faults of an
unregulated
marketplace, but he more profoundly subjects its
would-be
regulators to a withering critique. He reveals their
self-interested
motives for wanting to regulate the fair and,
more
importantly, he lays bare their sheer incompetence to manage
the
marketplace successfully.
In contrast
to what happens in Jonson's earlier
masterpieces,
Volpone and The Alchemist, in Bartholomew Fair the
apparent
forces of disorder triumph at the end and frustrate the
efforts of
those who try to impose order on their economic
activities.8 As grave as Jonson's doubts about an
unregulated
market may
be, in the end he seems to suggest that a regulated
market would
be a good deal worse, if only because the regulators
are no better
than the regulated. For all its faults, the market
in Jonson's
portrayal answers to deep-seated needs in human
nature and he
ultimately seems to recognize the value of the
freedom it
offers, as well as the fact that freedom is compatible
with its own
kind of order. In short, Jonson seems to have an
inkling of
the idea of spontaneous order as it was to be
developed in
the twentieth century by the Austrian economist
Friedrich
Hayek. Bartholomew Fair offers an example in miniature
of a
community that is ordered, not by regulations imposed from
above by an
outside authority, but by self-regulating principles
5
generated
from within, a system of checks and balances that
relies on the
common material interests of its participants to
bring about
their harmony. Bartholomew Fair may be the first
portrait in
literary history of how a free market operates.
If Jonson
displays unusual sympathy for the nascent free
markets of
the Renaissance in Bartholomew Fair, the reason may be
that he
recognized that as a professional dramatist and actor he
was a
participant in a marketplace himself. Bartholomew Fair may
be the
headquarters of charlatans and thieves, but it is also the
home of
playwrights and actors. Jonson seems to have come to
realize that
if marketplaces are regulated, the theatre will
always be
among the first to come under government control and
the results
will not always be beneficial to the theatre and its
public.9 In Bartholomew Fair Jonson seems to
allow his
professional
commitment to the theatre to overcome his
longstanding
aristocratic contempt for the world of commerce. He
even seems to
have tried to shape a new dramatic form in
Bartholomew
Fair that would mirror the freedom and spontaneity of
the
marketplace it represents. The apparent formlessness of the
play actually
answers to an inner law--the spontaneous order of
the free
market--and its artful artlessness suggests in aesthetic
terms how the
principles of order and freedom can be
reconciled.10 Bartholomew Fair thus explores the issue
of law on
several
levels at once--religious law, political law, economic
6
law, and
aesthetic law--and charts the complex interaction of
these various
legal domains.
ii.
At first
sight, Bartholomew Fair seems to carry on
vigorously
the critique of the nascent market economy of the
Renaissance
Jonson had developed in earlier plays like Volpone
and The
Alchemist. Like many of his contemporaries, Jonson was
particularly
suspicious of the move in his day from a conception
of wealth
based on land to one based on money. In Volpone, he
satirizes the
way money begets money in the devious schemes of
Volpone and
Mosca, who appear to be utterly unproductive and
living like
parasites off the wealth of others. In The
Alchemist,
Jonson images the world of trade and finance as a
giant con
game, in which greedy and ambitious men on the make are
seduced into a
variety of get-rich-quick schemes by the
charlatans
Face and Subtle. To Jonson, the act of market
exchange
looks like alchemy, the fraudulent promise to create
value out of
nothing, to change something worthless into
something
precious, as the alchemist claims to transmute base
metals into
gold.
Jonson is
thus a good illustration of Hayek's claim that the
market
economy looks like magic to people who do not understand
the
complexities of economic transactions. Ignorant of the
genuine
contributions entrepreneurs make to economic life by
7
their
risk-taking and ferreting out knowledge of market
conditions,
many people picture the businessman as a kind of
sorcerer. As
Hayek writes:
Such distrust
and fear have, since antiquity and in many
parts of the
world, led ordinary people as well as socialist
thinkers to
regard trade not only as distinct from material
production,
not only as chaotic and superfluous in itself, .
. . but also
as suspicious, inferior, dishonest, and
contemptible.
. . . Activities that appear to add to
available
wealth, 'out of nothing', without physical
creation and
by merely rearranging what already exists,
stink of
sorcery. . . . That a mere change of hands should
lead to a
gain in value to all participants, that it need
not mean gain
to one at the expense of the others (or what
has come to
be called exploitation), was and is nonetheless
intuitively
difficult to grasp. . . . As a consequence of
all these
circumstances, many people continue to find the
mental feats
associated with trade easy to discount even
when they do
not attribute them to sorcery, or see them as
depending on
trick or fraud or cunning deceit.11
As Hayek
points out, this kind of distrust of the businessman is
particularly
acute early in economic history, for example, during
the
Renaissance, when capitalist principles were just beginning
to dissolve
feudalist ways of doing business and many people were
8
confused and
alienated by the initial results.
Jonson is an
especially interesting example of early
hostility to
the market economy. He seems to have spent much of
his career in
reaction to and rebellion against what can be
described as
his lower middle-class origins.12 His
stepfather
was a
bricklayer, and by following in his footsteps, Jonson was
exposed early
in his life to the world of trade. Fortunately
Jonson
received an excellent education at the famous Westminster
School in
London, and when the opportunity presented itself, he
pursued the
typical middle-class path of rising in society by
using his
wits and learning.13 Probably in
1594, he entered the
world of the
professional theatre, first as an actor and soon as
a playwright.
The theatre was one of the more advanced segments
of the
Elizabethan economy, employing financial and marketing
techniques
that were sophisticated for the time (for example, the
theatres were
early examples of joint-stock companies and were
heavily
capitalized by Renaissance standards). As the cases of
Marlowe and
Shakespeare had already shown, the Elizabethan
theatre
offered a marvelous opportunity for a talented young man
to make money
and a name for himself.14
Though Jonson
prospered in the theatre world, he seems to
have resented
the source of his income and success. He
repeatedly
shows signs of believing that the conditions of the
commercial
theatres forced him to compromise his art to please
9
the debased
taste of the public. He made fun of the way other
playwrights
(including Shakespeare) catered to their audience and
he often got
embroiled in controversy as a result. He sought to
purge the
theatre of what he perceived to be its vulgarity,
conceiving of
himself as the playwright who would restore
classical
dignity to drama, in part by consciously imitating
Roman models
in many of his plays. Jonson was the first English
playwright to
bring out a published edition of his plays (in
1616), no
doubt with a view to proving that his works were not
the mere
ephemeral products of the entertainment marketplace but
literature of
lasting value.15
Throughout
his literary career, Jonson did everything he
could to
escape the commercial theatre world, above all turning
to
aristocratic and royal patronage as an alternative to his
bourgeois
source of income in the entertainment business. He
wrote poetry
in quest of aristocratic patrons and even in his
dramatic
career, he alternated between writing for the public
theatres and
writing for the royal court.16 He
was the great
master of the
court masque, and was richly rewarded over the
years by
James I for his contribution to royal entertainments.
Aside from
the financial advantages of writing for the court,
Jonson seems
to have been attracted by the prospect of composing
with
aristocratic taste in mind, rather than the lower- and
middle-class
taste that prevailed in the commercial theatres.
10
The stage
history of Bartholomew Fair encapsulates Jonson's
theatrical
career in miniature. The play was first staged on
October 31,
1614 at one of the public theatres, the Hope, and
then the
following evening it was performed at the court before
James I.17 In the published version of the play,
both the
prologue and
the epilogue are addressed to James, and Jonson
shamelessly
flatters the king for having taste superior to the
mob's. In
this one play, Jonson for once seems to have it both
ways.18 He gives his popular audience the kind
of vulgar
spectacle it
craves and then he repackages the same material for
a royal
audience, presenting it in a condescending fashion and
implying that
he and his aristocratic patrons are above this sort
of foolery
and derive their enjoyment from looking down upon
it.19
In that
sense, Bartholomew Fair seems to embody everything
that was
conservative and backward-looking in Jonson's drama. He
seems to side
with the aristocracy and its world of feudal
privilege
against the rising middle class and its world of money
and commerce.20 For critics with socialist leanings, it
is
tempting to
read Bartholomew Fair as a proto-Brechtian work, as
if Jonson
were criticizing the early signs of capitalism from the
left. But
insofar as the play satirizes the commercial world, it
does so from
the right. One must remember that even (and
especially)
in Marxist terms, capitalism was the progressive
11
force in
Jonson's day, working to dissolve centuries of
antiquated
feudal privilege and unleash unprecedentedly
productive
forces. At first glance, Jonson's view of capitalism
in
Bartholomew Fair thus seems reactionary. Turning his back on
his own class
origins, and scorning the original source of his
theatrical
success, he identifies with an aristocracy we now know
to have been
dying. In fact, Bartholomew Fair does a remarkable
job of
showing how chaotic and morally dubious the new world of
trade and
money looked to the old order it was displacing.
Jonson seems
to give a very negative portrait of the protocapitalist
world in
Bartholomew Fair. The marketplace apparently
flouts all
conventional notions of morality, decency, and fair
play. Jonson
portrays the fair as basically a den of thieves.
Ezekiel
Edgworth is a professional cutpurse, but Jonson does not
present him
as the one criminal among a group of honest
tradespeople.
On the contrary, the seemingly honest merchants at
the fair work
hand in hand with Edgworth, identifying victims for
him, setting
them up for the actual robberies, and helping him to
dispose of
the stolen goods.
Even when the
merchants of Bartholomew Fair are not
participating
in outright thievery, Jonson presents them as
looking to
cheat their customers. He makes the familiar charge
that the
merchants adulterate their products to increase their
profits. Many
of the tradespeople deal in suspicious merchandise
12
(see, for
example, II.ii.3-9), but the prize for adulteration at
the fair goes
to Ursula the pig-woman. She also does a thriving
business in
alcohol and tobacco on the side, and instructs her
assistant
Mooncalf on how to stretch their supplies and increase
their sales:
But look
to't, sirrah, you were best; threepence a pipeful I
will ha' made
of all my whole pound of tobacco, and a
quarter of a
pound of coltsfoot mixed with it too, to eke it
out. . . .
Then six and twenty shillings a barrel I will
advance o' my
beer, and fifty shillings a hundred o' my
bottle-ale; I
ha' told you the ways how to raise it. Froth
your cans
well i' the filling, at length, rogue, and jog
your bottles
o' the buttock, sirrah, then skink out the
first glass,
ever, and drink with all companies, though you
be sure to be
drunk; you'll misreckon the better, and be
less ashamed
on't. (II.ii.86-95)
The density
of detail in this passage suggests that Jonson was
uncannily
familiar with the dark side of Renaissance commerce.
Perhaps in
his apprentice days in the theatre, he helped run a
food
concession during intermission.
But Jonson's
critique of the marketplace goes deeper than
simple
charges of thievery and cheating. He is not interested
only in
aberrations of the market principle, moments when
unscrupulous
individuals might be said to depart from the decent
13
norms of
business as usual. Jonson's satire goes right to the
heart of the
market principle itself. He is extremely skeptical
about the way
products are merchandised, and displays a
surprisingly
sophisticated understanding of how tradespeople are
able to prey
upon the desires of potential customers. Jonson's
portrait of
the fair suggests a world that has gone mad with
consumerism
and the young gallant Bartholomew Cokes is the
maddest of
them all, Jonson's image of everything that can go
wrong when a
market liberates the desires of its customers.21
Jonson is
particularly struck by the power of what we would call
advertising.
He shows the customers at the fair continuously
bombarded by
the din of the merchants hawking their wares: "What
do you lack?
What is't you buy? What do you lack? Rattles,
drums,
halberts, horses, babies o' the best? Fiddles of the
finest?"
(II.ii. 28-30).
Cokes's
tutor, Humphrey Wasp, describes him as mesmerized by
the power of
advertising, the many signs displayed at the fair:
Why, we could
not meet that heathen thing, all day, but
stayed him;
he would name you all the signs over, as he
went, aloud;
and where he spied a parrot or a monkey, there
he was
pitched, with all the little long-coats about him,
male and
female; no getting him away! (I.iv.102-6)
As a result
of being bombarded with advertising, Cokes has his
desires
awakened and he cannot control his appetites:
14
If he go to
the Fair, he will buy of everything to a baby
there; and
household-stuff for that too. . . . And then he
is such a
ravener after fruit! You will not believe what a
coil I had
t'other day to compound a business between a
Catherine-pear
woman and him about snatching! (I.v.100-106)
In Cokes,
Jonson creates an unforgettable portrait of the
helpless
consumer, caught in the webs of advertising and
overwhelmed
by the wealth of goods now available in the
Renaissance
marketplace:
And the three
Jew's trumps; and half a dozen o' birds, and
that drum (I
have one drum already) and your smiths (I like
that device
o' your smiths very pretty well) and four
halberts--and
(le'me see) that fine painted great lady, and
her three
women for state, I'll have. (III.iv.67-71)
Wasp sees the
logical conclusion of Cokes's infinite desire:
"No, the
shop; buy the whole shop, it will be best, the shop, the
shop!"
(III.iv.72-73). Cokes recognizes the truth of Wasp's
charge--"I
do want such a number o' things" (III.iv.82)--and
finally asks
one merchant: "What's the price, at a word, o' thy
whole shop,
case and all, as it stands" (III.iv.129-30).
Without
skipping a beat, Leatherhead calculates the sum: "Sir, it
stands me in
six and twenty shillings sevenpence halfpenny,
besides three
shillings for my ground" (III.iv.131-32). This is
Jonson's
image of the new world of capitalism--everything has its
15
price in
money and everything is up for sale. To emphasize the
point, and
suggest that even human flesh can be bought in the
marketplace,
Jonson makes prostitution an integral part of the
fair. He
presents the marketplace as a deeply confused and
confusing
realm, a topsy-turvy world in which moral values are
inverted and
characters lose their bearings. As the consumer par
excellence,
Cokes ends up completely bewildered and disoriented
by his
experience at the fair: "By this light, I cannot find my
gingerbread-wife
nor my hobby-horse man in all the Fair, now, to
ha' my money
again. And I do not know the way out on't, to go
home for
more. . . . Dost thou know where I dwell?" (IV.ii.20-22,
25).
Assaulted from all sides by thieves, charlatans, and
advertisers,
Cokes utterly loses all sense of his own identity:
"Friend,
do you know who I am?" (IV.ii.71).
iii.
Jonson
develops a strong case against the market in
Bartholomew
Fair. He shows the amorality, venality, lawlessness,
and even the
criminality of the unregulated marketplace, thus
portraying a
world that seems to cry out for some form of
economic
regulation. And he includes in the play characters who
vehemently
condemn the fair and call for its regulation. But for
once Jonson
asks the follow-up question: who are these would-be
regulators
and are they fit to impose law and order on the
sprawling
marketplace they profess to despise? This is not a
16
trivial
question, and just by posing it, Jonson takes a
significant
step toward arguments that eventually were to be
developed by
economists like Adam Smith in favor of free markets.
The fact that
an unregulated market may have its faults and
disadvantages
does not in itself prove that a regulated market
will not have
its faults and disadvantages as well, and perhaps
end up
producing an even worse situation. In Bartholomew Fair
Jonson
finally gets around to scrutinizing the proponents of law
and order, to
see if they really are capable of living up to
their promise
of improving the world.
The simplest
case Jonson examines is Humphrey Wasp, who is
devoted to
restraining the appetites of his charge Cokes. Given
how freely
young Bartholomew spends his money, one can sympathize
with
Humphrey's attempts to be strict with him. But Wasp
responds to
Cokes's excesses with moral indignation. As his name
indicates,
Humphrey is waspish, always ready to fly off into fits
of anger and
quarrel with anyone in sight. It is thus by no
means clear
that his disposition is preferable to Cokes's or any
less
passionate and excessive. Bartholomew is a fool but he is a
relatively
harmless fool, and unlikely to cause much trouble for
others. By
contrast, Wasp is always provoking conflict and
getting himself
and others into difficulties. Mistress Overdo
views him as
an enemy of the "conservation of the peace" (I.v.12)
and instructs
him: "do you show discretion" (I.v.10-11),
17
eventually
pleading with him: "govern your passions" (I.v.21).
Here is the
irony of Wasp's role in the play: he sets himself up
as the
governor of his charge's passions, and yet he cannot
govern his
own. He presents himself as the champion of law and
order, and
yet he is in fact one of the chief forces for disorder
in the play.
The game of
vapours that breaks out in Act IV is very funny
and borders
on absurdity, but it may reflect a serious threat
Jonson sensed
in his world. In his image of people contradicting
each other
merely for the sake of contradicting each other,
Jonson offers
a comic reflection of Elizabethan and Jacobean
society--a
nation riven by all sorts of competing claims and
authorities,
political and religious. With the benefit of
historical
hindsight, we can read Bartholomew Fair today and see
the forces at
work in the London of the play that were in a few
decades to
plunge Britain into civil war. But Jonson himself
evidently saw
the Puritan Revolution coming, or at least had an
inkling of
what might spark it. As the game of vapours gets out
of hand and
starts to become dangerous, Mistress Overdo once
again tries
to rein in Wasp and his quarrelsome companions:
"conserve
the peace" (IV.iv.101). She sees the direction in
which his
waspishness is leading: "Are you rebels? Gentlemen?
Shall I send
out a sergeant-at-arms or a writ o' rebellion
against
you?" (IV.iv.128-29). The threat of revolution does seem
18
to be
hovering in the background of Bartholomew Fair, and Jonson
traces it not
to the childish appetites of a Bartholomew Cokes
but to the
fiery indignation of a Humphrey Wasp.
In fact, the
only way to contain Wasp's rebellious anger
turns out to
be to place him in the stocks. In another ironic
twist, the
would-be restrainer ends up in restraint. The irony
is not lost
even on the dim-witted Bartholomew; learning of his
tutor's
disgrace, Cokes is no longer disposed to honor his
authority:
"Hold your peace, Numps; you ha' been i' the stocks, I
hear"
(V.iv.88). Wasp immediately recognizes the implications
for his
continued rule over his charge: "Does he know that? Nay,
then the date
of my authority is out; I must think no longer to
reign, my
government is at an end. He that will correct another
must want
fault in himself" (V.iv.90-91). Wasp's last statement
may represent
Jonson's great discovery in the course of thinking
through and
writing Bartholomew Fair.22 The
principle that only
a superior,
indeed a perfect, person has the right to regulate
others does
not apply just to Wasp in the play. In fact it is
the governing
principle of Jonson's critique of all the would-be
forces of law
and order in the play, and especially Zeal-of-the-
Land Busy.23
iv.
The fact that
a fanatical Puritan is one of the chief
critics of
the marketplace in Bartholomew Fair suggests that
19
Jonson may
well be reconsidering his earlier attacks on the new
economic
freedom of his era.24 Jonson's
portrayal of Busy makes
it clear that
arguments against the free market are often
ultimately
based in religion, not economics. Busy's objections
to
advertising and to the products displayed at the fair are
rooted in his
Puritanism and specifically his hatred of idolatry:
For long
hair, it is an ensign of pride, a banner, and the
world is full
of those banners, very full of banners. And
bottle-ale is
a drink of Satan's, a diet-drink of Satan's,
devised to
puff us up and make us swell in this latter age
of vanity, as
the smoke of tobacco to keep us in mist and
error. But
the fleshly woman which you call Ursula is above
all to be
avoided, having the marks upon her of the three
enemies of
man: the world, as being in the Fair; the devil,
as being in
the fire; and the flesh, as being herself.
(III.vi.27-35)
Busy is
convinced that the economic activity at the fair is not
merely
disordered and unregulated but sinful and evil. For him
the fair is
"wicked and foul" and "fitter may it be called a foul
than a
Fair" (III.vi.79-80). He claims to know what is good for
his fellow
human beings and what is bad for them. Indeed he
thinks he
knows better than they themselves what is in their
interest.
Thus he arrogates to himself the right to tell people
what they can
and cannot do in the marketplace. Jonson himself
20
had a strong
streak of moralism and in many of his plays he sets
himself up as
the arbiter of good and evil. But his creation of
the character
of Busy seems to reflect a growing doubt about the
social
consequences of moralistic attitudes.
Busy is a
busy-body, constantly meddling in other people's
affairs and
trying to reorder their lives. He criticizes pride
but he is
exceedingly proud himself, and enjoys lording it over
others. It
surely was not lost on Jonson that it was people like
Busy who were
attacking the London theatres and constantly trying
to shut them
down. Anyone who condemns attempts to please
consumers is
eventually going to get around to condemning the
theatre. In
short, if the Puritans were enemies of the
marketplace,
Jonson may have begun to wonder if the marketplace
was his
friend. The way Jonson sets up the terms of Bartholomew
Fair,
economic freedom is pitted against religious tyranny.
Jonson
portrays Busy as an overreacher, a man who sets
himself up as
a god over his fellow human beings and fails to
live up to
his inflated self-image. But he also shows that Busy
is a
hypocrite. He condemns the money-making activities of the
marketplace
and yet he is obsessed with money-making himself.25
In general,
as if he were anticipating Max Weber's The Protestant
Ethic and the
Spirit of Capitalism, Jonson shows the Puritans
devoting
themselves quasi-religiously to the acquisition of
wealth. In
the fifth act, Dame Purecraft finally reveals that
21
she is
"worth six thousand pound" (V.ii.46)--a huge sum in those
days--and she
goes on to explain the devious means by which she
accumulated
the money:26
These seven
years I have been a willful holy widow, only to
draw feasts
and gifts from my entangled suitors. I am also
by office an
assisting sister of the deacons, and a
devourer,
instead of a distributor, of the alms. I am a
special maker
of marriages for our decayed brethren with
rich widows,
for a third part of their wealth, when they are
married, for
the relief of the poor elect; as also our poor
handsome
young virgins with our wealthy bachelors or
widowers to
make them steal from their husbands when I have
confirmed
them in the faith, and got all put into their
custodies.
(V.ii.48-57)
Here the
Puritan Dame Purecraft begins to sound a good deal like
one of
Jonson's conmen in earlier plays.
But Purecraft
defers to Busy as the chief money-maker of
them all:
Our elder,
Zeal-of-the-Land, would have had me, but I know
him to be the
capital knave of the land, making himself rich
by being made
feoffee in trust to deceased brethren, and
cozening
their heirs by swearing the absolute gift of their
inheritance.
(V.ii.59-63)
Jonson gives
Busy mercantile origins; the fact that he began as a
22
baker
(I.iii.107-112) stresses his kinship to the tradespeople he
later
condemns. Toward the end of the play, in Busy's debate at
the puppet
show, the Puppet Dionysius points out that the
Puritans are
heavily involved in the clothing trade and thus
implicated in
the very luxuries they rail against (V.v.75-84).27
By revealing
the Puritans to be hypocrites, Jonson
undermines
their authority as advocates of law and order. He
further shows
that Busy is willing to bend the law to suit his
own purposes.28 Despite their claim to adhere strictly
to
religious
law, the Puritans turn out to be extremely flexible
when it comes
to interpreting the law in accord with their own
desires. When
Win Littlewit expresses her deep longing for roast
pig at the
fair, her mother at first urges her to resist the
temptation,
but soon is willing to endorse the desire "if it can
be any way
made or found lawful" (I.vi.27-28). Dame Purecraft
enlists her
spiritual advisor Busy to find a way of pronouncing
Win's
appetite lawful. Busy sets to work interpreting the law,
but it is a
difficult case:
Verily, for
the disease of longing, it is a disease, a
carnal
disease, or appetite, incident to women; and as it is
carnal, and
incident, it is natural, very natural. Now pig,
it is a meat,
and a meat that is nourishing, and may be
longed for,
and so consequently eaten; it may be eaten; very
exceeding
well eaten. But in the Fair, and as a Bartholomew
23
pig, it
cannot be eaten, for the very calling it a
Bartholomew
pig, and to eat it so, is a spice of idolatry.
(I.vi.43-49)
Purecraft
urges a liberal understanding of the law on her fellow
Puritan:
"Good Brother Zeal-of-the-Land, think to make it as
lawful as you
can" (I.vi.54-55). Busy proves equal to the task:
It may be
eaten, and in the Fair, I take it, in a booth, the
tents of the
wicked. The place is not much, not very much,
we may be
religious in midst of the profane, so it be eaten
with a
reformed mouth, with sobriety, and humbleness; not
gorged in
with gluttony or greediness. (I.vi.63-67)
The ease with
which Busy is able to interpret the law to
legitimate
desire raises doubts about the whole status of law in
the play. The
advocates of the law present it as the moral
alternative
to the marketplace. The law is supposed to be
immutable and
incorruptible, as opposed to the mutable and
corrupt
marketplace, where everyone is on the make and values and
prices change
from minute to minute. But Jonson shows the
Puritan
characters making and remaking the law before our eyes.
The law loses
much of its prestige when it is revealed to be
changeble and
even pervertible according to the dictates of
desire. In
the puppet show debate, lawfulness turns out to be a
matter of
semantics, the product of mere wordplay and not of any
fundamental
principle. The puppet has an easy answer to Busy's
24
charge that
the theatre lacks lawfulness:
BUSY I mean
no vocation, idol, no present lawful calling.
PUPPET
DIONYSIUS Is yours a lawful calling? . . .
BUSY Yes,
mine is of the spirit.
PUPPET
DIONYSIUS Then idol is a lawful calling.
LEATHERHEAD
He says, then idol is a lawful calling! For
you called
him idol, and your calling is of the spirit.
(V.v.49-50,
52-55)
By the time
Jonson is through ringing changes on the word law in
Bartholomew
Fair, the term has become virtually meaningless. The
law no longer
appears to stand majestically above the marketplace
and hence
entitled to regulate it. Rather the law is negotiated
and
renegotiated just like any other item at the fair.
Jonson's
antipathy to the Puritans led him to probe deeper
into their
hostility to the marketplace. The gamester Quarlous
notes that
Busy, as a Puritan, rejects all tradition and claims
to remain
true to a purified notion of an original faith: "By his
profession,
he will ever be i' the state of innocence, though,
and childhood;
derides all antiquity; defies any other learning
than
inspiration; and what discretion soever years should afford
him, it is
all prevented in original ignorance" (I.iii.129-33).
Busy's hatred
for the marketplace grows out of his Puritan
hostility to
tradition. For Busy the marketplace is the locus of
business as
usual, where men and women go about satisfying the
25
desires they
have always had. By catering to what people want,
the market
stands in the way of the moral reformation Busy is
striving for.
Unlike the merchants of Bartholomew Fair, he will
not accept
human beings as he finds them, but rather wants to
remake them
in one grand revolutionary effort. That is why Busy
images the
moral reformation of the world in terms of an
apocalyptic
abolition of the marketplace. He defines himself as:
"one
that rejoiceth in his affliction, and sitteth here to
prophesy the
destruction of fairs and May-games, wakes and
Whitsun ales,
and doth sigh and groan for the reformation of
these
abuses" (IV.vi.78-80). Jonson understands that Busy
rejects the
world as such and wants to see it fundamentally
remade. His
hostility to life as usual dictates his hostility to
business as
usual, and hence demands the overthrow of the
marketplace
as the center of existing abuses. Jonson saw how
deeply
revolutionary the Puritan mentality was, and events in a
few decades
were to prove him right.
The Puritan
revolutionary impulse manifests itself even on
the level of
language. Refusing to accept the common names of
things, the
Puritans become involved in a laughable process of
trying to
rename everything, including themselves: "O, they have
all such
names, sir; he was witness for Win here--they will not
be called
godfathers--and named her Win-the-fight. You thought
her name had
been Winifred, did you not?" (I.iii.116-19). In a
26
play in which
signs are often more important than substance, the
impulse to
rename things is tantamount to the impulse to remake
them. Thus,
although Busy appears to be an advocate of law and
order, like
Wasp he turns out to be a force for disorder. Again
like Wasp, he
is guity of incivility, as Quarlous makes clear in
his final
summary of the Puritan character: "Away, you are a
herd of
hypocritical proud ignorants, rather wild than mad,
fitter for
woods and the society of beasts than houses and the
congregation
of men. You are. . . outlaws to order and
discipline"
(V.ii.38-41).
v.
Adam Overdo
is Jonson's most interesting example of the need
to tame the
regulatory spirit. Like Wasp and Busy, he claims to
devote
himself to repressing passions and correcting excesses in
others, and
yet he is in the grip of passion himself and goes
from one
excess to another.29 Though he
presents himself as a
disinterested
servant of "the public good" (II.i.9; see also
V.ii.84),
Jonson suggests that he may be just a social climber,
using his
office to advance his own cause. Wasp reproaches
Mistress
Overdo: "Why mistress, I knew Adam, the clerk, your
husband, when
he was Adam scrivener, and writ for twopence a
sheet, as
high as he bears his head now, or you your hood, dame"
(IV.iv.141-43).
Overdo is a little man who puffs himself up with
the thought
that he is better than his fellow human beings and
27
seeks to prove
it by imposing order on their lives.
Unfortunately
for Overdo, he is not equal to the task he
sets himself
as the overseer of law and order. He prides himself
on his
judgment of human nature and his ability to spy into the
souls of men.
But Jonson shows him making one mistake after
another.30 He thinks that the robber Edgworth is in
fact a
"civil"
young man and tries to become his patron (II.iv.30).
Overdo is
particularly susceptible to anyone who will flatter his
ego, as
becomes evident in his encounter with Trouble-All, a man
who went mad
when Overdo dismissed him from his position in the
Court of
Piepowders at the fair. Trouble-All is unwilling to do
anything
without a written warrant from Overdo, a form of madness
that initally
strikes the Justice as evidence of Trouble-All's
wisdom:
"What should he be, that doth so esteem and advance my
warrant? He
seems a sober and discreet person!" (IV.i.23-24).
Overdo's
continuing misjudgment of the other characters in the
play makes
him a laughing-stock and ultimately undermines his
authority. As
Quarlous points out to him at the end of the play:
"your
'innocent young man' you have ta'en care of all this day,
is a cutpurse
that hath got all your brother Cokes his things,
and helped
you to your beating and the stocks" (V.vi.72-75).
Overdo claims
to be able to bring moral order to the world, and
yet he cannot
tell good from evil, as he mistakes criminals and
madmen for
model citizens. The complete collapse of his regime
28
occurs when
he goes to punish a group of prostitutes and
discovers
that one of them is his own wife in disguise.
When Overdo
speaks out against the fair's merchandise,
chiefly
alcohol and tobacco, one might be tempted to sympathize
with his
criticism, but Jonson goes out of his way to caricature
Overdo's
complaints and make them sound foolish. Busy inveighs
against the
products of the fair because he is trying to save the
souls of its
customers; Overdo is trying to save their bodies.
He cautions
against alcoholic beverages: "Thirst not after that
frothy
liquor, ale; for who knows when he openeth the stopple
what may be
in the bottle? Hath not a snail, a spider, yea, a
newt been
found there?" (II.vi.11-14). Overdo is also on an
anti-smoking
crusade: "Neither do thou lust after that tawny
weed,
tobacco. . . Whose complexion is like the Indian's that
vents it! . .
. And who can tell, if, before the gathering and
making up
thereof, the alligator hath not pissed thereon?"
(II.vi.21-26).
Overdo may be raising slightly different doubts
about the
safety of alcohol and tobacco products than we hear
today, but
the basic principle is the same. He distrusts
anything
exotic and loves to dwell on the worst-case scenario.
He goes on to
lament the amount of money he thinks is wasted on
these luxury
products: "Thirty pound a week in bottle-ale! Forty
in tobacco!
And ten more in ale again" (II.vi.77-78). At times
Overdo sounds
much like a contemporary campaign against smoking:
29
"Hence
it is that the lungs of the tobacconist are rotted, the
liver spotted,
the brain smoked like the backside of the pigwoman's
booth
here" (II.vi.39-41).
Overdo thus
offers a puritanism of the body to correspond to
Busy's
puritanism of the soul. In either case, the result is the
same: strict
government control over the everyday activities of
ordinary
people, with prohibition as the ultimate goal. If it is
not clear
from the way Jonson has the Justice characteristically
overdo his
tirade against alcohol and tobacco that he is making
fun of this
health-conscious puritanism,31 one
might recall that
Overdo's
attack on drinking and smoking is identical to Puritan
strictures
against theatre-going ("it's bad for you," "it wastes
your
money," and so on). Evidently by the time of writing
Bartholomew
Fair, Jonson had begun to wonder whether concern for
saving souls
and bodies would result in the end of the
entertainment
business as he knew it.
Perhaps the
most remarkable aspect of Jonson's critique of
authority in
Bartholomew Fair is his anticipation of Hayek's
theory about
the benefits of dispersing knowledge in society.
Overdo's
scheme to disguise himself and spy out enormities at the
fair is an
attempt to gain the knowledge he would actually need
to regulate
the marketplace. Modelling himself on "a worthy
worshipful
man" (II.i.11-12), probably "Thomas Middleton, the
reforming
Lord Mayor of London in 1613-14,"32 Overdo
uses his
30
masquerade to
seek out a synoptic, even a panoptical view of the
economic
world of London:
Marry, go you
into every alehouse, and down into every
cellar;
measure the length of puddings, take the gauge of
black pots
and cans, aye, and custards with a stick; and
their
circumference with a thread; weigh the loaves of bread
on his middle
finger; then would he send for 'em, home; give
the puddings
to the poor, the bread to the hungry, the
custards to
his children; break the pots and burn the cans
himself; he
would not trust his corrupt officers; he would
do't himself.
(II.i.16-24)
As Overdo
describes the Mayor's procedures, they seem a model of
regulating
the economy. He oversees all economic activity in the
city, down to
the last detail, and he uses his comprehensive
knowledge to
correct all injustices, with a particular care to
redistributing
goods to the poor and needy. The actions of
Overdo's
model are in fact what most people have in mind when
they talk
about correcting the failures of the market.
But
Bartholomew Fair is a comedy and Overdo is one of the
chief targets
of its satire, not a model of enlightened rule in
Jonson's
eyes. There is more than something faintly absurd about
the Justice's
view of a centrally planned economy. Indeed he
inadvertently
reveals the impossibility of the task. For a
government to
regulate the economy successfully, it would need
31
knowledge of
every detail of its working, all the way down to
weighing
every single loaf of bread to the ounce. But in fact
this
knowledge in all its complexity of detail is never available
to any one
person or centralized authority, as Jonson's example
suggests. The
mayor's idea of regulating the economy is to do
every job
himself, a telling image for the ultimate consequences
of government
intervention in the economy. The mayor violates
the principle
of the division of labor, which is the foundation
of any
advanced economy. In fact, the market works precisely by
dispersing
knowledge of economic phenomena among a myriad of
people and
using the pricing mechanism to coordinate their
efforts.33 The central thrust of entrepreneurial
activity is the
creation, or
at least the ferreting out, of knowledge, and this
process works
best precisely when it is not centralized, but pits
many
individuals against each other, in active competition (with
success
rewarded and failure punished in financial terms).
Recognizing
this point was Hayek's great contribution to the
so-called
economic calculation debate concerning socialism,
inaugurated
by his teacher, Ludwig von Mises, in the 1920s.34
Without going
into the details of this debate, one may say that
events in the
Soviet Union and elsewhere in the formerly
communist
world would appear to have vindicated the Austrian
economists
Mises and Hayek in their claim that true economic
calculation
is impossible in the absence of open markets and the
32
monetary
accounting they make possible. The Soviet economy
eventually
collapsed precisely because its central planning
proved unable
to coordinate, or even just to ascertain, all the
economic data
involved in a modern system of production and
distribution.
As the Russian economist Yuri Maltsev writes:
"When
the Soviet government set 22 million prices, 460,000 wage
rates, and
over 90 million work quotas for 110 million government
employees,
chaos and shortages were the inevitable result."35
Jonson surely
could not have anticipated the economic calculation
debate
concerning socialism; he would not even have known what
socialism is.
But he does look forward to the core of the Mises-
Hayek
argument, that would-be government regulators are simply
inadequate to
the task of overseeing the complex division of
labor in a
modern economy.
Jonson
specifically presents the problem of government
regulation of
the economy as a problem of knowledge. Overdo's
model mayor
has ambitious plans for restructuring the economy,
and yet he
himself does not "trust his corrupt officers"; hence
he gets
involved in the hopeless task of doing everything in the
economy by
himself. Overdo realizes the limitations of his
knowledge as
a government official:
For (alas) as
we are public persons, what do we know? Nay,
what can we
know? We hear with other men's ears; we see
with other
men's eyes; a foolish constable or a sleepy
33
watchman is
all our information; he slanders a gentleman by
virtue of his
place, as he calls it, and we by the vice of
ours, must
believe him. . . . This we are subject to, that
live in high
place; all our intelligence is idle, and most
of our
intelligencers, knaves; and by your leave, ourselves
thought
little better, if not arrant fools, for believing
'em.
(II.i.24-34)
By impeaching
his sources of knowledge, Overdo undermines his
authority to
regulate the marketplace. He points out all the
reasons why
government officials are not in a position to know
the relevant
economic facts, and his scheme to gain access to
that
knowledge proves to be a complete and humiliating failure
for him.
Overdo's noble-sounding vision of an all-seeing and
all-knowing
government turns out to be a fantasy and a farce.
Government
officials are limited and fallible human beings
themselves
and just as likely to make mistakes as merchants in
the
marketplace. The only and the crucial difference between
civil
servants and private businessmen is that when a central
planner makes
a mistake, he is likely to disrupt the whole
economy, and
not just his own business.
vi.
In the eyes
of government officialdom, the disguised Overdo
appears to be
a criminal, and, he like Wasp and Busy, ends up in
the stocks.
When he himself is charged with "enormity," Overdo
34
sees the
irony of the situation: "Mine own words turned upon me
like
swords" (III.v.203). The would-be regulators in the play
are not happy
when they themsevles fall under the power of
government
regulation. Wasp objects to the intrusion of
strangers
into his business: "Cannot a man quarrel in quietness,
but he must
be put out on't by you?" (IV.iv.147-48). When he
learns that
the intruders are "His Majesty's Watch," Wasp is not
pleased with
the government's panoptical surveillance: "A body
would think,
an you watched well o'nights, you should be
contented to
sleep at this time o'day" (IV.iv.149-52). Wasp
would like a
respite from the all-seeing eye of the government.
One gets the
sense from Bartholomew Fair that Jonson, several
times the victim
of government surveillance himself, sympathized
with this
position.
The madman
Trouble-All provides the inverted mirror image of
an
all-seeing, all-knowing government in Jonson's play. He is
the perfect
subject of a panoptical regime,36 the
man who will
not make a
move without express warrant from a government
official:
"he will do nothing but by Justice Overdo's warrant: he
will not eat
a crust, nor drink a little, nor make him in his
apparel
ready. His wife, sir-reverence, cannot get him make his
water or
shift his shirt without his warrant" (IV.i.51-54).37
Here finally
is someone who would presumably heed Overdo's
invectives
against alcohol and tobacco. But Trouble-All provides
35
the reductio
ad absurdum of the world of government regulation.
He reveals
what would be the disturbing but logical result of a
total command
economy, in which no human action took place
without a
government decree. Even Overdo is appalled at what he
has done to
transform Trouble-All into a figure wholly dependent
on authority
for guidance: "If this be true, this is my greatest
disaster!"
(IV.i.55).
From his
encounter with Trouble-All, Overdo learns a very
Hayekian
lesson, what one might call the law of unintended
consequences:
"To see what bad events may peep out o' the tail of
good
purposes!" (III.iii.12-13).38 Jonson
seems to measure his
characters by
the results of their actions, not their motives.
The
do-gooders in Bartholomew Fair are the cause of most of the
difficulties
in the play and all the near-disasters. And the
reason is
that in Jonson's view, life in general and the
marketplace
in particular are just too complicated for these
simplistic
and moralistic regulatory schemes to work
successfully.
Actions have unanticipated consequences and
efforts to
control events only succeed in producing disorder and
eventually
chaos. Overdo must learn to accept life for what it
is, admit his
own limitations, and abandon his plans for
perfecting
and reforming the world.39 As
Quarlous tells him in
the end:
"remember you are but Adam, flesh and blood! You have
your frailty;
forget your other name of Overdo, and invite us all
36
to supper.
There you and I will . . . drown the memory of all
enormity in
your biggest bowl at home" (V.vi.93-97). Jonson
presents the
festive spirit of comedy as the triumph of humanity
and freedom
over petty moralism and officious government.40
The spokesmen
for authority in Bartholomew Fair want to
contrast the
ordered and stable world of law with the chaotic and
unstable
world of the marketplace. But Jonson's satiric view of
the would-be
regulators suggests a different perspective. He
seems to
contrast the rigid and stultifying world of law with the
fluid and
vibrant world of the marketplace. As happens in many
comedies, in
Bartholomew Fair Jonson portrays the dead weight of
the law as
the obstacle standing in the way of the characters
satisfying
their normal human desires. The law appears in the
first speech
in the play proper, appropriately in stilted legal
language:
"Here's Master Bartholomew Cokes, of Harrow o'the hill,
i'the county
of Middlesex, Esquire, takes forth his license to
marry
Mistress Grace Wellborn of the said place and county"
(I.i.3-5).
The first manifestation of the power of law in
Bartholomew
Fair significantly takes the form of a marriage
license.41 Jonson emphasizes the way the law gives
power to some
human beings
to dispose of the lives of others, with men usually
ruling over
women, and parents over children. Jonson makes one
of the marriage
plots turn on the fact that Grace Wellborn is the
legal ward of
Adam Overdo, and thus his to dispose of in
37
marriage. In
Grace's statement of her position, Jonson stresses
the
arbitrariness of her status and her dissatisfaction with it.
When asked how
she became Overdo's ward, Grace bitterly replies:
"Faith,
through a common calamity: he bought me, sir; and now he
will marry me
to his wife's brother, . . . or else I must pay
value o' my
land" (III.v.260-62). Evidently, human beings are
bought and
sold in the legal world just as commodities are bought
and sold in
the marketplace.42 Far from
providing an alternative
to the
venality of the market, the law seems to operate according
to the same
principles. Indeed in Jonson's presentation, the law
seems worse
than the market: it gives people the right to buy and
sell other
human beings, and not just commodities.
Women
especially do not fare well in the legal world of
Bartholomew
Fair. In their homes, they seem to be the chattle
property of
their husbands, fathers, and guardians. That perhaps
explains why
the women in the play are particularly eager to go
to the fair.
For them, entering the marketplace represents a
kind of
liberation. Jonson suggests this point comically when
several of
the women quite literally enter the marketplace, that
is, are
enlisted into prostitution. He certainly is not
advocating
prostitution as a way of life, but he approaches the
subject with
greater freedom and less moralism than Justice
Overdo does.
Half jokingly, Jonson has the bawd Captain Whit try
to teach Win
Littlewit that she ought to prefer the life of a
38
prostitute to
that of a married woman: "de honest woman's life is
a scurvy dull
life" (IV.v.26-27). The chief reason Whit offers
for his claim
is that a wife leads "de leef of a bondwoman,"
whereas he
tells Win: "I vill make tee a free-woman" (IV.v.29-
30). In
Bartholomew Fair, the legal institution of marriage is
presented as
a form of slavery, while entering the marketplace as
a prostitute
appears to be a form of freedom.
Viewed from
one perspective, prostitution is one of the
chief vices
of the fair, but in the full context of the play, it
is difficult
for the advocates of law and order to use
prostitution
as an argument against the marketplace. Jonson does
everything he
can to efface the distinction between prostitutes
and married
women, as he shows men buying women in marriage.43
Quarlous
thinks of the legal institution as in fact a way to
marry money
itself: "Why should not I marry this six thousand
pound. . . ?
And a good trade too, that she has beside, ha?. . .
It is money
that I want; why should I not marry the money, when
'tis offered
me? I have a license and all; it is but razing out
one name and
putting in another" (V.ii.69-75). Quarlous also
reveals the
arbitrariness of legal documents: they are supposed
to embody the
sanctity of the law, but it is an easy matter to
doctor them.44 A legal document can mean almost
anything,
depending on
how the writing is altered. There are a number of
"blank
checks" in the form of legal documents circulating in
39
Bartholomew
Fair,45 including the open warrant Overdo thinks
he
is giving to
the madman Trouble-All but which actually falls into
the hands of
Quarlous. He immediately grasps the possibilities
of having the
justice's signature on a blank document: "Why
should not I
ha' the conscience to make this a bond of a thousand
pond,
now?" (V.ii.112-13). But Quarlous finds a better use for
this blank
document: to certify transferring Grace as a ward from
Overdo to
himself. Thus he, not Overdo, becomes the beneficiary
when Grace
must pay money to her guardian for the right to marry
Winwife.
Jonson's
criticism of the law is double-edged. On the one
hand, the law
appears to be too rigid; with its iron hand, it
tries to
define all human relationships, and keep people confined
to the
straight and narrow path. But on the other hand, the law
appears to be
too flexible and arbitrary; with a stroke of a pen,
a man can
alter a legal document and redefine a human
relationship.
Ultimately in Jonson's portrayal the problem with
the law is
its mindless legalism. The law tries to codify the
fluidity of
life into binding rules, but as Jonson shows in
Bartholomew
Fair, once a legal document is written down, it can
all too
easily be rewritten and hence become fluid itself. As
Jonson
presents it, the law seems to alternate between defining
the terms of
human life too tightly and defining them too
loosely. In
either case, the law gives some human beings a
40
despotic
power over others.
vii.
The fact that
Jonson develops such a devastating critique of
the law and
its representatives in Bartholomew Fair does not mean
that he is
blind to the failings of the marketplace. On the
contrary, as
we have seen, he was well-aware of all the
shortcomings
of the fair and the emerging market economy it
represents--if
anything, he exaggerates them. But when Jonson
compares the
would-be regulators of the market with the people
they wish to
regulate, on balance he seems to side with the
latter. On
the whole, the apparently unregulated markets of the
fair stand
for order in the play, while their would-be regulators
actually
prove to be the motive forces for disorder. Jonson
presents the
merchants as generally cooperating with one another,
if only in
schemes to defraud and rob their customers. They are
of course not
saints, but they are not quite sinners either, at
least not in
the evil terms in which men like Busy and Overdo try
to portray
them. Many of the merchants provide legitimate goods
and services
to their customers and Jonson presents the fair as a
life-enhancing
force. After all, people flock to it voluntarily
and thus it
must be performing some sort of service to the
community.
By contrast,
the characters who try to shut down the fair
are the
spoilsports of the play, and must be defeated for the
41
comic ending
to be possible. In seeking to please the public,
the fair may
cater too much for Jonson's taste to the baser
appetites of
the London populace. And yet all the opponents of
the fair have
to set against these natural desires is their anger
and their
moral indignation, as Wasp, Busy, and Overdo repeatedly
prove. And in
Jonson's portrayal, this anger turns out to be
just as
irrational as desire and more socially disruptive. As we
have seen,
Jonson suggests at several points that religious and
moral
hostility to the marketplace easily translates into a
revolutionary
impulse and may in fact tear the fabric of society
apart.
In earlier
plays like Volpone and The Alchemist, Jonson had
dwelled upon
the ways in which the emerging market economy was
itself a
revolutionary force, threatening to upset the settled
order of
society and above all to overthrow the social hierarchy
by making
poor men rich and rich men poor. But in Bartholomew
Fair, Jonson
appears to rethink his view of the social effects of
the market
economy, or at least to refine it. He now dwells on
the ways in
which the market allows people to negotiate their
difference
and thus actually helps to bring them together. The
market
provides an image of social harmony in Bartholomew Fair,
not a harmony
without conflict, but one in which the tensions
among the characters
can be worked out as the participants in the
fair come to
realize their common economic interests.
42
Jonson shows
the way the market tends to level out
differences.
Bartholomew Fair is a place where people from all
walks of life
meet and interact freely.46 The
market does a
particularly
good job of levelling social pretensions. Winwife
tries to put
on airs when he first comes to the fair and acts as
if the
commercial world were beneath him: "That these people
should be so
ignorant to think us chapmen for 'em! Do we look as
if we would
buy gingerbread? Or hobby-horses?" (II.v.10-12).
But Quarlous
points out that to enter the fair is to accept it on
its own terms
and acknowledge kinship with the rest of the
customers:
"Why, they know no better ware than they have, nor
better
customers than come. And our very being here makes us fit
to be
demanded as well as others" (II.v.13-15). In fact the only
people the
fair works to exclude are zealots like Busy and Overdo
who will not
accept its terms and admit their common humanity.
Unlike the
merchants, they are uncompromising and refuse to
negotiate
their differences with others.47 By
contrast, in the
fair money
provides a common currency by means of which people
can settle
their accounts, financial and otherwise.
It would be
easy to overstate the extent to which Jonson
anticipates
the arguments in favor of free markets developed long
after his
death. He has a weak grasp of how free markets
operate,
which is only natural for someone who was in effect
witnessing
their troubled birth. He has only the barest sense of
43
how markets
are self-regulating mechanisms; he does at least have
some inkling
of how Bartholomew Fair, left to itself, constitutes
a kind of
rough-and-tumble order. But one could not credit
Jonson with
anticipating the full concept of spontaneous order as
it was to be
developed by Mises, Hayek, and other Austrian
economists.
Where Jonson does genuinely anticipate later
economic
thinking is in his critique of efforts to regulate the
marketplace.
Here his thinking becomes rather sophisticated
economically,
as he shows how efforts to reform the market
actually tend
to make things worse, and how efforts to impose
order on the
economy only succeed in making it more chaotic. In
short, his
negative case for not regulating the market is much
stronger than
any positive case he makes for leaving the market
to regulate
itself. This is only to be expected of a writer who
had extensive
experience with government regulation of the
economy,
living as he did in a world still largely feudal and
mercantilist,
but only limited experience with genuine economic
freedom,
which was only just beginning to emerge in his day.
Though Jonson
could not fully understand how merchants regulate
themselves,
he knew enough to be suspicious of the kind of people
who seek to
regulate them.
Jonson's
sympathy for the free market in Bartholomew Fair
makes the
play unusual if not unique in his dramatic output. As
we have seen,
in other plays he can be highly critical of the
44
marketplace
and its effect on society. But it seems that for
once in this
play he decided to give the market its due and
explore what
kind of case could be made for economic freedom, or
at least
against economic regulation. If this seems like an
implausible
concern for Jonson, one must remember that by
participating
in the English Renaissance theatre, he was
experiencing
one of the most sophisticated and advanced segments
of the
economy of his time, and also one that was heavily
regulated by
the government. Jonson's experience in the theatre
in fact put
him in an excellent position to examine the question
of government
regulation of the economy, of the law versus the
marketplace.
His new-found sympathy for the marketplace seems to
have grown
out of a new recognition of the way his theatre world
was
inextricably intertwined with the emerging market economy of
his day.
NOTES
. T. S. Eliot
claimed that Bartholomew Fair had "hardly a plot at all." See his
"Ben
Jonson" in Selected Essays (New York: Harcourt, Brace, 1950), p. 134. See
also Richard
Levin, The Multiple Plot in English Renaissance Drama (Chicago:
University of
Chicago Press, 1971), p. 202: "We cannot find any central line of
action which
holds everything together." In his Introduction to English
Renaissance
Comedy (Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press, 1999), Alexander
Leggatt
quotes Terry Hands, who, in connection with his 1969 production of the
play for the
Royal Shakespeare Company, described it as "an enormous canvas with
no particular
focus" (p. 138). I quote Bartholomew Fair from the edition of
Gordon
Campbell in Ben Jonson, The Alchemist and Other Plays (Oxford: Oxford
University
Press, 1995), with citations incorporated in the text.
. See Levin,
Multiple Plot, p. 208 and Eugene M. Waith, ed., Ben Jonson:
Bartholomew
Fair (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1963), p. 2.
. Martin
Butler says that Jonson manages "to give an illusion of randomness
which is
carefully and rigorously premeditated." See his The Selected Plays of
Ben Jonson
(Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1989), Vol. 2, p. 147.
. See Waith,
Bartholomew Fair, p. 20.
. See
Leggatt, English Renaissance Comedy, pp. 136-37, E. A. Horsman, ed.,
Bartholomew
Fair (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1960), p. xi, and Anne
Barton,
"Shakespeare and Jonson," in Essays, mainly Shakespearean (Cambridge,
UK:
Cambridge
University Press, 1994), p. 294: "[Bartholomew Fair] maintains the most
delicate
balance between order and chaos, between structure and a seemingly
undisciplined
flow which is like the random, haphazard nature of life itself."
. For
information on the actual Bartholomew Fair and Renaissance fairs in
general, see
Peter Stallybrass and Allon White, The Politics and Poetics of
Transgression
(Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1986), especially Chapter 1.
Stallybrass
and White correctly emphasize the modernity of the fair and its role
as a
harbinger of developing market principles, and they criticize a nostalgic
view of the
fair as a backward-looking, medieval institution.
. See Waith,
Bartholomew Fair, p. 3 and William W. E. Slights, Ben Jonson and
the Art of
Secrecy (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1994), pp. 149, 152,
and 211 (note
34).
. See
Stallybrass and White, Transgression, p. 66, Jonas Barish, Ben Jonson and
the Language
of Prose Comedy (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1967), pp.
212-13, and
Katharine Eisaman Maus, Ben Jonson and the Roman Frame of Mind
(Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1984), p. 132.
. For
examples of government regulation during the Elizabethan period that
proved
disastrous to the theatre companies and to Jonson in particular, see David
Riggs, Ben
Jonson: A Life (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1989), pp.
33-34.
10. For an
excellent attempt to sketch out the structural pattern of Bartholomew
Fair, see the
section on the play in Levin's Multiple Plot, especially pp. 211-
12.
11. Friedrich
Hayek, The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism (Chicago:
University of
Chicago Press, 1988), pp. 90, 91, and 93.
12. This is
one of the main themes of David Riggs's biography of Jonson; see
especially
Jonson, pp. 4-5.
13. On
Jonson's ambition, see Riggs, Jonson, pp. 2-3.
14. See
Riggs, Jonson, pp. 24-25.
15. On
Jonson's motives for bringing out the 1616 Folio, see Barish, The
Antitheatrical
Prejudice (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1981), p.
138, Leggatt,
English Renaissance Comedy, p. 135, and Stallybras and White,
Transgression,
p. 75.
16. For the
tension running throughout Jonson's theatrical career, see Riggs,
Jonson, pp.
63-64, 69, 234, Stallybrass and White, Transgression, pp. 66-79,
Barish,
Antitheatrical Prejudice, pp. 132-54, and Kate McLuskie, "Making and
Buying: Ben
Jonson and the Commercial Theatre Audience," in Julie Sanders, Kate
Chedgzoy, and
Susan Wiseman, eds., Refashioning Ben Jonson: Gender, Politics and
the Jonsonian
Canon (London: Macmillan, 1998), pp. 134-54.
17. See
Waith, Bartholomew Fair, p. 205, Butler, Selected Plays, p. 148, Leggatt,
English
Renaissance Comedy, p. 136, and Campbell, Alchemist, p. 503. As these
editors point
out, a measure of the "popularity" of the Hope Theatre is the fact
that it was
still being used for the "sport" of bear-baiting.
18. See
Horsman, Bartholomew Fair, pp. xii-xiv, Butler, Selected Plays, p. 149,
and Julie
Sanders, Ben Jonson's Theatrical Republics (London: Macmillan, 1998),
pp. 92-93.
19. See
McLuskie, "Making and Buying," pp. 144-45.
20. This was
L. C. Knights' view of Jonson and his "fellows" in his famous book,
Drama and
Society in the Age of Jonson (London: Chatto & Windus, 1937). See
especially p.
7: "The standards of judgement that they brought to bear were not
formed in
that new world of industrial enterprise. They belonged to an older
world which
was still 'normal,' a world of small communities."
21. On the
stimulation of desire in Renaissance fairs, see Stallybrass and White,
Transgression,
pp. 38-40.
22. This
point is reinforced by the fact that the Wasp-Cokes story in Bartholomew
Fair may
reflect events that actually happened when Jonson accompanied Sir Walter
Raleigh's son
Wat as his tutor on a trip to Paris. See Riggs, Jonson, pp. 206-7,
Barish, Prose
Comedy, p. 213, and Butler, Selected Plays, p. 137: "during this
trip the
pupil triumphantly exposed his mentor to public view in a cart while he
was
prostrated in a bout of drunkenness."
23. On the
parallels between Wasp and Busy, see Levin, Multiple Plot, pp. 204-5.
24. Riggs
(Jonson, p. 195) suggests that in creating the character of Zeal-ofthe-
Land Busy,
Jonson may have had a personal score to settle with a particular
Puritan
preacher named Robert Milles.
25. See
Slights, Art of Secrecy, p. 158.
26. See
Slights, Art of Secrecy, p. 159.
27. See
Leggatt, English Renaissance Comedy, p. 139.
28. See
Slights, Art of Secrecy, pp. 157-58.
29. See
Levin, Multiple Plot, pp. 206-7.
30. See
Leggatt, English Renaissance Comedy, p. 149 and Slights, Art of Secrecy,
pp. 154, 169.
31.
Evaluating Overdo's attack on tobacco is complicated by the fact that it
resembles
sentiments expressed in James I's Counterblast to Tobacco (published in
1604). It is
difficult to determine if these parallels are meant to raise Overdo
in our esteem
or lower James, but on balance the latter possibility seems more
likely.
Barish, Prose Comedy, pp. 319-20 (note 23), details a number of the
parallels
between Overdo's speech and James's Counterblast, but "wonders what
Jonson's
royal patron thought of this scene." Horsman, Bartholomew Fair, p. xxi,
is even more
skeptical: "It is tempting to suspect that the attack on tobacco was
added to
please James I, whose views were known, at the court performance; but
this seems
ruled out by the uncomplimentary resemblance between James and the
Justice."
Sanders, Theatrical Republics, pp. 94-95, also discusses the
complexities
of the parallels between Overdo and James I.
32. Gordon
Campbell's note in his edition (Alchemist, p. 507, line 12). See also
Butler,
Selected Plays, pp. 137 and 530. The claim that the mayor referred to
was Thomas
Hayes can be found in Horsman, Bartholomew Fair, pp. xviii-xix and
Michael
Jamieson, ed., Ben Jonson: Three Comedies (Harmondsworth, UK: Penguin
Books, 1966),
pp. 481, 483. Slights (Art of Secrecy, pp. 153, 209, note 14)
settles the
identification in favor of Middleton.
33. Leggatt,
English Renaissance Comedy, p. 150, speaks of the "principle of
dispersed
attention" in Bartholomew Fair. In a very different context,
Stallybrass
and White make an argument similar to Hayek's: the traditional view
of the fair
"consigns the subordinate classes to contesting state and class power
within a
problematic which has positioned them as ignorant, vulgar, unitiated--as
low. In fact
'low' knowledge frequently foregrounds not only the actual
conditions of
production but also the conditions of bodily pleasure"
Transgression,
p. 43). If I am reading them correctly, Stallybrass and White
are in effect
making the point of Austrian economics that consumers are in a
better
position than government officials to know what their desires are and how
best to
satisfy them.
34. The
socialist calculation debate began with Mises' essay "Die
Wirtschaftsrechnung
in sozialistischen Gemeinwesen," published in the Archiv für
Sozialwissenschaften,
47 (1920). For an English translation by S. Adler of this
essay, see
Ludwig von Mises, Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth
(Auburn, AL:
Praxeology Press, 1990). For Hayek's key contribution on the
problem of
knowledge, see his "The Use of Knowledge in Society" in his
Individualism
and Economic Order (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1948).
This volume
also contains several other chapters on the socialist calculation
debate
(chapters VII-IX). For further contributions to the debate from the free
market side,
see Ludwig von Mises, Socialism (New Haven: Yale University Press,
1951) and
Volume 10 in The Collected Works of Friedrich Hayek, Socialism and War
(Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1997). For overviews of the socialist
calculation
debate, see Trygve J. B. Hoff, Economic Calculation in the Socialist
Society
(Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1981) and David Ramsay Steele, From Marx to
ises:
Post-Capitalist Society and the Challenge of Economic Calculation
(LaSalle, IL:
Open Court, 1992).
35. See
Maltsev's foreword to Mises' Economic Calculation, p. vi.
36. Leggatt,
English Renaissance Comedy, describes Trouble-All as a "citizen of
an
authoritarian state" and "a figure Kafka might have invented"
(pp. 150-51).
37. See also
IV.ii.4-5, 86-87, 98-99, IV.vi.4, 114-15.
38. On the
importance of the "unintended result" in the play, see Levin,
Multiple
Plot, p. 211.
39. See
Horsman, Bartholomew Fair, p. xii.
40. See
Barish, Prose Comedy, p. 236 and Maus, Roman Frame, p. 134.
41. On the
importance of the marriage license in the play, see Sanders Theatrical
Republics, pp.
90-91 and Slights, Art of Secrecy, pp. 161-62.
42. See
Leggatt, English Renaissance Comedy, p. 145.
43. See
Leggatt, English Renaissance Comedy, p. 147 and Slights, Art of Secrecy,
pp. 160, 163,
166.
44. For a
good discussion of the dubious status of legal documents in the play,
see Slights,
Art of Secrecy, pp. 154, 170.
45. See
Leggatt, English Renaissance Comedy, p. 140.
46. See
Barish, Prose Comedy, pp. 189, 231. Horsman (Bartholomew Fair, p. 189)
quotes a near
contemporary description of the fair (1641): "Hither resort people
of all sorts,
High and Low, Rich and Poore, from cities, townes, and countrys; of
all sects,
Papists, Atheists, Anabaptists, and Brownists: and of all conditions,
good and bad,
vertuous and vitious, Knaves and fooles, Cuckolds and
Cuckoldmakers,
Bauds, and Whores, Pimpes and Panders, Rogues and Rascalls, the
little
Loud-one and the witty wanton."
47. Slights
(Art of Secrecy, pp. 160-61) makes a similar point and in support of
it quotes the
Table-Talk of Jonson's friend John Selden: "Disputes in Religion
will never be
ended, because there wants a Measure by which the Business would be
54
decided: The
Puritan would be judged by the Word of God: If he would speak
clearly, he
means himself. . . . Ben Johnson Satyrically express'd the vain
Disputes of
Divines by Inigo Lanthorne, disputing with his puppet in a
Bartholomew
Fair. It is so; It is not so: It is so, It is not so, crying thus
one to
another a quarter of an Hour together."